Martin Gammon
A. Gomez
A. Gomez, Money
Girl, 2019
Oliver Cole Gallery
Is art a good investment? The recent mega-auctions in New York have
brought out the siren song that art often outperforms other asset classes like
real estate, while the Wall Street Journal declared that art achieved a 10.6
percent return in 2018 based on Art Market Research’s Art 100 Index, outpacing
all other categories. One would think then that many savvy investors should be
allocating funds to this glamorous asset class.
Most art market pundits will advise collectors to “buy what you
love,” and not speculate on making a profit on acquisitions, but nevertheless
imply that substantial appreciation on par with traditional asset classes is a
hallmark of the art market in the post-war period.
Every season each major auction house has at least one or two outstanding
estates, put together over several decades, that achieve substantial
appreciation in some portions of their aesthetic choices—like the Mayers of
Chicago, who fortuitously bought Robert Rauschenberg’s Buffalo II (1964) from
Leo Castelli in 1964 for $16,900, and which sold last month for $88.8 million
with fees—that appear to give credence to the inevitability of enormous asset
appreciation. However, given that a mere dozen or so estates appear to make the
grade in any given year at the evening sales in New York and London, what might
that mean for the thousands of other art collectors in the same generation who
somehow have not come out for the party?
Dark matter
It is possible to make money on art, but the more specific question
is whether it is an attractive asset class for a middle market investor with a
typical 5–10 year horizon analogous to other alternative investments. One of
the chief challenges to adjudicating the merits of art as an investment, then,
is having a transparent picture of its true annualized rate of return and its
relative correlation with other asset classes in promoting a diversified
portfolio.
Most of the established benchmarks for demonstrating this return
are understandably focused on the observable price trends at auction as the
only securely available dataset. However, this fixation on the available sales
data tends to gloss over the often invisible background from which this data
arises.
Much like the universe itself, one of the chief opacities to
understanding the true economics of the art market is the enormous influence of
‘dark matter’ on asset prices. This dark matter consists in the vast number of
artworks that have not, cannot, or will not, come to market, but nevertheless
apply an invisible gravitational pull on the asset prices we can actually
observe. These reservoirs of non-transactional works serve to artificially
underwrite scarcity and aggravate demand, and both support the rarified prices
of that very thin sliver of works that do come to market and distort the
appearance of returns on investment for the category as a whole. In short, this
unseen dark matter is just as important as the few star lots grabbing headlines
every auction season.
A large portion of this dark matter comes in the form of museum
accessions, which in effect serve as primordial black holes that sequester
masterpieces from the marketplace through donations and museum acquisitions,
but for the most part they will never be sold again. The recent shibboleth that
Salvator Mundi (ca. 1500) is the “last” Leonardo da Vinci painting in private
hands implies the fewer than 20 recognized examples in public collections will
never return to the marketplace, and amplifies the price accordingly. Indeed,
the enormous growth of museum collections, which has winnowed the ranks of
masterpieces available since World War II, has contributed to the appearance of
scarcity and an enormous inflation effect on those rarified asset prices.
Museum accessions also go hand in hand with the powerful effect of
philanthropic giving for highly taxable estates. One can be quite sure that the
recent buyers of David Hockney’s Portrait of an Artist (Pool with Two Figures)
(1972) and Jeff Koons’s Rabbit (1986)—both of which hammered at $80 million—are
not buying them for investment, or planning to turn around and sell them for
$160 million in 5 or 10 years. There is a powerful philanthropic driver beyond
the investment horizon that inflates asset prices for trophy artworks in the
marketplace. If you are generating billions in capital gains or other income,
you may be perfectly comfortable acquiring an $80-million artwork if the
subsequent donation of that work to your non-profit foundation mitigates other
tax liabilities on your balance sheet. This gambit drives most of the high-value
acquisitions we see at auction, of works that will likely never return to the
market again. Most of the major contemporary collectors spending at that
rarified level are not planning to re-sell, and certainly are not buying for
investment in the traditional sense, but rather allocating a portion of their
wealth to assets that allow them to enjoy the blandishments of a private museum
or major philanthropic gift, accompanied by a huge tax write-off that this
inflation effect helpfully holds aloft.
A second field where dark matter resides is in the vaults of
dealers’ unsold inventory of primary market material, as well as a select group
of market makers who own large positions in a given artist’s work. In both
cases, these entities are often active bidders and third-party guarantors who
support prices in their chosen sector, in order to provide stable benchmarks
for that unsold inventory. If these large reservoirs of material were not
temporarily off the market, prices would crater as supply would quickly outstrip
demand.
Both of these reservoirs of dark matter—trophy works destined for
museum accession or philanthropic donation and unsold inventory—serve to keep
prices afloat and maintain artificial scarcity for the thinly traded population
of works that do come to market each season. One nagging uncertainty to
ascertaining future growth then is if any of these reservoirs were to be
breached—if deaccessions suddenly became more widespread, the tax laws changed,
or substantial private inventories were liquidated—then this artificial
scarcity would quickly be nullified.
Another, and less understood, reservoir of this dark matter, but
possibly the most consequential, is the vast number of private
collections—acquired either at auction or the primary market—which remain
stubbornly underwater, or are worth less than their combined acquisition and
liquidation costs.
It may come as a shock to some, but after many years of appraising
collections assembled in the last 30 years, I would conservatively estimate
that a substantial majority would realize less than they cost to acquire if
they were to be liquidated, given the enormous transactional costs associated
with buying and selling art.
A significant portion of past acquisitions typically do not come to
market, and this enormous deadweight loss is like an invisible lodestar on the
apparent annualized rate of return of artworks that are often only calculated
from actual repeat sales. The works that come for resale are on balance mostly
the winners that have achieved significant price inflation, making them a poor
proxy for the true asset appreciation for the category.
This enormous reservoir of underperforming assets, scattered across
numerous private balance sheets and thus difficult to discern, does not
normally come into the marketplace to demonstrate its eroding state of
depreciation, except in piecemeal fashion through eventual death, divorce, or
duress. This enormous, hidden cache of dark matter is the unseen lodestar
significantly depressing the true annualized rate of return for artworks as a
whole.
Sample selection
bias
We can catch a glimpse of this elusive third form of dark matter
and its impact on prices in the groundbreaking art economics paper by
University of Southern California professor Arthur Korteweg and two European
colleagues, Roman Kräussl and Patrick Verwijmeren, which exposes the potential
sample selection bias of some art indices, like Mei Moses (now owned by
Sotheby’s), which employ repeat sales to calculate annualized returns for
various segments of the art market. The paper’s hypothesis is that artworks
that have significant price appreciation are more likely to come to market and
result in higher observed returns relative to the population at large, leading
to a sample selection bias that must be adjusted accordingly, yielding a much
less sanguine investment profile.
In order to demonstrate this effect, Korteweg et al. set out to
construct their own art data set of repeat sales drawn from the Blouin Art
Sales Index, and identify 2.3 million paintings sold between 1960 and 2010 for
their sample population. Seeking out all identifiable repeat sales, and leaving
out indeterminate matches, buy-ins, and other outliers, they locate 32,928
paintings which have a total of 69,103 repeat sales (some more than once).
It is particularly noteworthy that less than two percent of this
population (32,928 paintings out of 2.3 million sold at auction between 1960
and 2010), have demonstrably sold more than once in this 50-year period. What
happened to the other 98 percent? Many remain in private estates and have been
gifted to museums, and many could have been sold privately, but even granting
those caveats, less than two percent is a very slim recursion rate for
appearing again at auction over half a century, especially during a period that
has anecdotally been construed as one of the longest bull markets in art
history. One corollary implication of Korteweg’s paper is that at least some of
those paintings have not been reoffered because they would incur a loss and have
languished as underperforming assets compared to the cohort who have enjoyed
repeat sales. This gets at a fundamental flaw of art indices that do not adjust
for this selection bias.
Building an alternative model that does account for this bias, the
paper found that the average annual rate of return for paintings in their
sample drops from 8.7 percent to 6.3 percent, and the corresponding Sharpe
Ratio (a measure of risk vs. return) drops from a robust 2.7 percent to a
meagre 1.1 percent. They conclude that a well-balanced investment portfolio,
taking into account this sample selection bias when compared to other asset
classes like stocks and bonds, would allocate exactly 0 percent of their assets
to paintings as a category. While paintings may have a modest annual adjusted
return of 6.3 percent between hammer prices, according to this model, the
enormous additional transactional costs further erode this picture to the point
that art as an investment vehicle may seem a contradiction in terms.
The eighty percent
rule
Art investment skeptics often underscore the price opacity and lack
of liquidity of the underlying asset, and the difficulty in picking winners,
among other factors that dampen the prospects of art as an investment vehicle.
However, there is also a much more straightforward structural challenge: the
enormous transactional costs of entering and exiting a position through the
auction markets.
Most market participants are aware that acquiring works at auction
is often the most cost-effective measure, as retail prices from dealers are
typically pegged at a significant premium to what is termed fair market value
at auction (usually measured as the hammer price plus buyer’s premium). A
simple calculation will indicate that the aggregate transactional costs of
entering and exiting an investment in this market are a substantial drag on any
prospective appreciation, which many investors may simply overlook in the
calculation of annualized returns.
Say you are a New York City resident who has $10,000 to invest in
the auction market. To stay within that budget, you would likely need to limit
your maximum bid to around $7,000 to cover the buyer’s premium (25% at most
houses: $1,750), New York sales tax (8.875%: $621) and shipping and handling
($629 for argument’s sake, to round out the total). So, your $10,000 allocation
is already saddled with a 30% depreciation at the very outset of the
investment, significantly weighing on its future prospects.
Bracketing aside any expenses for insurance, conservation, or other
carrying costs, after five years you elect to sell the same work, and you have
the unexpected windfall of an 80% return, or $12,600 from the original hammer
price of $7,000. Unless you have negotiated special terms, you will typically
owe the auction house a 10% seller’s commission (so, minus $1,260), 1.5%
insurance fee (minus $189), photo fee (minus $200), and shipping and handling
again (minus $629), for a net total of $10,322. The good news is you have a
modest return of $322, but you may still owe the 31.8% in capital gains tax on
collectibles on this portion (about $102.40), yielding a net return of about
$219 and change.
The above scenario assumes standard rates and sales tax charges
that may not apply in all cases, but as a benchmark it illustrates most market
participants need to have a minimum of an 80% baseline appreciation simply to
break even when entering and exiting an investment in the auction markets.
Many individual works and whole market categories have met or
exceeded this appreciation in short periods of time, but the general benchmark
from Korteweg’s study is an annual return of about 6.3%. This would suggest that many putative investments, in the absence of a
means to obviate these transaction costs, are operating at a significant loss. We find substantial
confirmation for this supposition from the extremely low recursion rates for
paintings in Korteweg’s 50-year sample. Most people don’t sell art if they’re
going to lose money in the process, and so it remains in limbo until their slow
appreciation may eventually exceed their cost basis, or they are forced to
sell. Thus, the specter of this vast field of dark matter looms behind the
apparent appreciation of observed prices.
Martin Gammon is the founder of Pergamon Art Group and the author
of “Deaccessioning and its Discontents: A Critical History” (MIT Press, 2018).
Related Stories
The 10 Best Booths at the Dallas Art Fair’s Online Edition
Will Online Viewing Rooms Increase Price Transparency at Galleries?
Jordan Casteel’s Bold Portraiture Is More Than a Market Trend
https://www.artsy.net/article/artsy-editorial-often-ignored-problem-buying-art-investment?utm_medium=email&utm_source=20047531-newsletter-editorial-daily-04-16-20&utm_campaign=editorial&utm_content=st-V
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario